Article Type
Changed
Mon, 01/02/2017 - 19:34
Display Headline
No hospital left behind? Education policy lessons for value‐based payment in healthcare

The United States is moving aggressively toward value‐based payment. The Department of Health and Human Services recently announced a goal to link 85% of Medicare's fee‐for‐service payments to quality or value by 2016.[1] Despite the inherent logic of paying providers for their results, evidence of the effectiveness of value‐based payment has been mixed and underwhelming. Recent reviews of pay‐for‐performancereflecting the emerging understanding of the complexities of designing successful programshave painted a more negative picture of their overall effectiveness.[2, 3] One study of over 6 million patients found that the Medicare Premier Hospital Quality Incentive Demonstration had no effect on long‐term patient outcomes including 30‐day mortality.[4] At the same time, research suggests that lower performing providers tend to have a disproportionate number of poor patients, many of whom are racial and ethnic minorities. Value‐based payment risks the dual failure of not improving health outcomes while exacerbating health inequities.

We have seen this movie before. In 2001, No Child Left Behind was enacted to improve quality and reduce inequities in K12 education in the United States. Much like healthcare, education suffers from uneven quality and wide socioeconomic disparities.[5] No Child Left Behind attempted to address these problems with new accountability measures. Based on the results from standardized tests, No Child Left Behind rewarded the highest performing schools with more funding while penalizing poor performing schools with reduced funding, and in some cases, forcing failing schools to cede control to outside operators.

In the aftermath of its implementation, however, it became clear that these incentives had not worked as intended. No Child Left Behind did not improve reading performance and was associated with improvements in math performance only for younger students.[6] These modest gains came at a high cost; consistent with teaching to the test, No Child Left Behind led to a shifting of instructional time toward math and reading and away from other subjects. It also led to widespread cheating, challenging the validity of observed performance improvements. Before No Child Left Behind was rolled out, the wealthiest school districts in the country spent as much as 10 times more than the poorest districts.[5] By penalizing the lowest performers, these gaps persisted. Schools were not given the support that they needed to improve performance.

The parallels to healthcare are striking (Table 1). Early results from Medicare's Hospital Value‐Based Purchasing and Readmission Reduction Program show that hospitals caring for more disadvantaged patients have been disproportionately penalized.[7] Similar reverse Robin Hood effects have been observed in incentive programs for physician practices.[8] Over time, financial incentive programs may substantially decrease operating revenue for hospitals and physicians caring for low‐income and minority communities. This could perpetuate the already large disparities in quality and health outcomes facing these populations. Although risk‐adjusting for socioeconomic status may alleviate these concerns in the short term, allowing low‐income or minority patients to have poorer health outcomes simply accepts that disparities exist rather than trying to reduce them.

Financial Incentive and Collaboration‐Based Programs in Healthcare and Education
Healthcare Education
National incentive programs Examples Hospital Value‐Based Purchasing Hospital Readmission‐Reduction Program No Child Left Behind
Hospital‐Acquired Conditions Penalty Program
Physician Value‐Based Payment Modifier
Approach toward improving performance Reimbursements are tied to quality and cost. Test‐based accountability: Results of standardized tests are used to determine levels of federal funding. Schools failing to meet testing goals are penalized with reductions in funding.
Bonuses are given to hospitals and providers that perform well on performance metrics. Low performers are penalized with lower reimbursements. Takeover of failing districts: Districts failing to make adequate yearly progress for 5 years in a row must implement a restructuring plan that may involve changing the school's governance arrangement, converting the school to a charter, or turning the school over to a private management company.
Unintended consequences Gaming Cheating to boost test scores.
Ignoring or neglecting areas of care that are unincentivized. Shift of instruction time toward math and reading.
Avoiding high‐risk or disadvantaged patients. States intentionally making assessment tools easier.
Stress among administrators, teachers, and students due to high‐stakes testing.
Collaboration‐based programs Examples Quality collaboratives Shanghai school system
Hospital engagement networks
Approach toward improving performance Improvement networks: High performing hospitals or providers are identified and work with other groups to improve patient treatment and the care process. Pairing of districts: High‐performing districts are paired with lower performing districts to exchange education development plans, curricula, and teaching materials.
Data sharing: Facilities collect and share data to monitor quality improvements and better identify best practices. Commissioned administration: A high‐performing school partners with low performers by sending experienced teachers and administrators to share successful practices and turn around their performance.
Example of success The Michigan Surgical Quality Collaborative was associated with a 2.6% drop in general and vascular surgery complications. Hospitals participating in the programs made improvements at a faster rate than those outside of the program. Zhabei District No. 8 School, located in an area with high crime rates and low student performance, was transformed from one of the lowest performing schools in its district to ranking 15 out of 30. Approximately 80% of the school's graduates go on to study at universities compared to the municipal average of 56%.

How then is it possible to improve the quality of care at lower performing hospitals without simultaneously designing an incentive system that hurts them? Lessons from the education policy are again instructive. Every 3 years the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development ranks countries by the performance of their 15‐year olds on a standardized test called the Program for International Student Assessment.[9] For the past 2 sets of rankings, Shanghai, China has topped the list. Like many attempts to generate international rankings, this one has its flaws, and Shanghai's top position has not been without controversy. For one, China is not ranked at the country‐level like other nations; yet, due to the city's status as a wealthy business and financial center, Shanghai certainly cannot be considered representative of the Chinese education system. Nevertheless, the story of how Shanghai reformed its education system and achieved its high position has important implications.

Prior to implementing reforms, Shanghai's rural outer districts struggled with less funding, high teacher turnover rates, and low test scores compared to wealthier urban districts. To reduce education disparities within the city's schools, the government of Shanghai enacted a number of policies aimed at bringing lower performers up to the same level as schools with the highest degree of student achievement.[10] The government gives schools a grade of A, B, C, or D based on the quality of their infrastructure and student performance. It then uses several programs to facilitate the exchange of staff and ideas among schools at different levels. One program pairs high‐performing districts with low‐performing districts to share education development plans, curricula, teaching materials, and best practices. Another strategycalled commissioned administrationinvolves temporary contracts between schools to exchange both administrators and experienced teachers. In addition to these approaches, the government sets a minimum level of spending for schools and transfers public funds to indigent districts to provide them with assistance to reach this level.

The notion that the very best can help the weak requires a sense of solidarity. This solidarity may falter in environments in which hospitals and physicians are in cutthroat competition. Though there will always be some tension between competition and collaboration, in most markets, competition between hospitals does not rule out collaboration. Policies can either relieve or reinforce the natural tension between competition and collaboration. This suggests that adopting reforms with the same intent as the Shanghai system is still possible in healthcare, especially through physician and other provider networks. The healthcare workforce has a rich history of cross‐organizational collaboration through mentorships, the publication of research, and participation in continuing medical education courses. The Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services' Hospital Engagement Networks, a program in which leading organizations have helped to disseminate interventions to reduce hospital acquired conditions, are an example of this approach. Quality collaborativesgroups of providers who collaborate across institutions to identify problems and best practices for improvementhave similarly shown great promise.[11] Similar approaches have been used by the Institute for Healthcare Improvement in many of their quality improvement initiatives.

Such collaboration‐based programs could be harnessed and tied to financial incentives for quality improvement. For instance, top‐performing hospitals could be incentivized to participate in a venue where they share their best practices with the lower performers in their field. Low performers, in turn, could be provided with financial assistance to implement the appropriate changes. Over time, financial assistance could be made contingent on quality improvements. By providing physicians and other providers with examples of what success looks like and assisting them with garnering the resources to reach this level, improvement would not only be incentivized, it might also become more tangible.

Although some hospitals and physicians may welcome changes to incentive systems, implementation of collaboration‐based programs would not be possible without a facilitator that is willing to underwrite program costs, provide financial incentivizes to providers, and develop a platform for collaboration. Large insurers are the most likely group to have the financial resources and widespread network to develop such programs, but that does not mean that they would be willing to experiment with this approach. This may especially be the case if cost savings and measurable improvements in quality are not immediate. Even though the results of collaboration‐based efforts have been promising, the implementation of these programs has been limited, and adoption in different contexts may not yield the same results. Collaboration‐based programs that have already shown success can serve as models, but they may need significant adaptations to meet the needs of providers in a given area.

Despite its promise, collaboration‐based strategies alone will not be enough to improve certain aspects of quality and value. Although providing physicians with knowledge on how to reduce unnecessary care, for example, could help limit overutilization, it is not sufficient to overcome the incentives of fee‐for‐service payment. In this case, broader payment reform and population‐based accountability can be paired with programs to encourage collaboration. For instance, the Blue Cross and Blue Shield of Massachusetts' Alternative Contract has used a combination of technical assistance, shared savings, and large quality bonuses to improve quality and reduce medical spending growth.[12] Collaboration‐based strategies should be seen as a complement to these broad, thoughtful reforms and a substitute for narrow incentives that encourage myopia and destructive competition.

Evidence from education and healthcare shows that penalizing the worst and rewarding the best will not shift the bell curve of performance. Such approaches are more likely to entrench and expand disparities. Instead, policy should encourage and incentivize collaboration to expand best practices that improve patient outcomes. Lessons from education provide both cautionary tales and novel solutions that might improve healthcare.

Disclosure: Nothing to report.

Files
References
  1. Burwell SM. Setting value‐based payment goals—HHS efforts to improve US health care. N Engl J Med. 2015;372:897899.
  2. Herck P, Smedt D, Annemans L, Remmen R, Rosenthal MB, Sermeus W. Systematic review: effects, design choices, and context of pay‐for‐performance in health care. BMC Health Serv Res. 2010;10:247.
  3. Houle SK, McAlister FA, Jackevicius CA, Chuck AW, Tsuyuki RT. Does performance‐based remuneration for individual health care practitioners affect patient care?: a systematic review. Ann Intern Med. 2012;157(12):889899.
  4. Jha AK, Joynt KE, Orav J, Epstein AM. The long‐term effect of premier pay‐for‐ performance on patient outcomes. N Engl J Med. 2012;366:16061615.
  5. Darling‐Hammond L. Race, inequality and education accountability: the irony of ‘no child left behind.’ Race Ethn Educ. 2007;10:245260.
  6. Dee TS, Jacob BA. The impact of no child left behind on students, teachers, and schools. In: Brookings Paper on Economic Activity. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution; 2010:149194.
  7. Ryan AM. Will value‐based purchasing increase disparities in care? N Engl J Med. 2013;369:24722474.
  8. Chien AT, Wroblewski K, Damberg C, et al. Do physician organizations located in lower socioeconomic status areas score lower on pay‐for‐performance measures? J Gen Intern Med. 2012;27:548554.
  9. Loveless T. Brown Center Chalkboard. Attention OECD‐PISA: your silence on China is wrong. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institute; 2013:48.
  10. Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development. Shanghai and Hong Kong: two distinct examples of education reform in China. In: Strong Performers and Successful Reformers in Education: Lessons from PISA for the United States. Paris, France: OECD Publishing; 2010:83115.
  11. Share DA, Campbell DA, Birkmeyer N, et al. How a regional collaborative of hospitals and physicians in Michigan cut costs and improved the quality of care. Health Aff. 2011;30:636645.
  12. Song Z, Rose S, Safran DG, Landon BE, Day MP, Chernew ME. Changes in health care spending and quality 4 years into global payment. N Engl J Med. 2014;371:17041714.
Article PDF
Issue
Journal of Hospital Medicine - 11(1)
Publications
Page Number
62-64
Sections
Files
Files
Article PDF
Article PDF

The United States is moving aggressively toward value‐based payment. The Department of Health and Human Services recently announced a goal to link 85% of Medicare's fee‐for‐service payments to quality or value by 2016.[1] Despite the inherent logic of paying providers for their results, evidence of the effectiveness of value‐based payment has been mixed and underwhelming. Recent reviews of pay‐for‐performancereflecting the emerging understanding of the complexities of designing successful programshave painted a more negative picture of their overall effectiveness.[2, 3] One study of over 6 million patients found that the Medicare Premier Hospital Quality Incentive Demonstration had no effect on long‐term patient outcomes including 30‐day mortality.[4] At the same time, research suggests that lower performing providers tend to have a disproportionate number of poor patients, many of whom are racial and ethnic minorities. Value‐based payment risks the dual failure of not improving health outcomes while exacerbating health inequities.

We have seen this movie before. In 2001, No Child Left Behind was enacted to improve quality and reduce inequities in K12 education in the United States. Much like healthcare, education suffers from uneven quality and wide socioeconomic disparities.[5] No Child Left Behind attempted to address these problems with new accountability measures. Based on the results from standardized tests, No Child Left Behind rewarded the highest performing schools with more funding while penalizing poor performing schools with reduced funding, and in some cases, forcing failing schools to cede control to outside operators.

In the aftermath of its implementation, however, it became clear that these incentives had not worked as intended. No Child Left Behind did not improve reading performance and was associated with improvements in math performance only for younger students.[6] These modest gains came at a high cost; consistent with teaching to the test, No Child Left Behind led to a shifting of instructional time toward math and reading and away from other subjects. It also led to widespread cheating, challenging the validity of observed performance improvements. Before No Child Left Behind was rolled out, the wealthiest school districts in the country spent as much as 10 times more than the poorest districts.[5] By penalizing the lowest performers, these gaps persisted. Schools were not given the support that they needed to improve performance.

The parallels to healthcare are striking (Table 1). Early results from Medicare's Hospital Value‐Based Purchasing and Readmission Reduction Program show that hospitals caring for more disadvantaged patients have been disproportionately penalized.[7] Similar reverse Robin Hood effects have been observed in incentive programs for physician practices.[8] Over time, financial incentive programs may substantially decrease operating revenue for hospitals and physicians caring for low‐income and minority communities. This could perpetuate the already large disparities in quality and health outcomes facing these populations. Although risk‐adjusting for socioeconomic status may alleviate these concerns in the short term, allowing low‐income or minority patients to have poorer health outcomes simply accepts that disparities exist rather than trying to reduce them.

Financial Incentive and Collaboration‐Based Programs in Healthcare and Education
Healthcare Education
National incentive programs Examples Hospital Value‐Based Purchasing Hospital Readmission‐Reduction Program No Child Left Behind
Hospital‐Acquired Conditions Penalty Program
Physician Value‐Based Payment Modifier
Approach toward improving performance Reimbursements are tied to quality and cost. Test‐based accountability: Results of standardized tests are used to determine levels of federal funding. Schools failing to meet testing goals are penalized with reductions in funding.
Bonuses are given to hospitals and providers that perform well on performance metrics. Low performers are penalized with lower reimbursements. Takeover of failing districts: Districts failing to make adequate yearly progress for 5 years in a row must implement a restructuring plan that may involve changing the school's governance arrangement, converting the school to a charter, or turning the school over to a private management company.
Unintended consequences Gaming Cheating to boost test scores.
Ignoring or neglecting areas of care that are unincentivized. Shift of instruction time toward math and reading.
Avoiding high‐risk or disadvantaged patients. States intentionally making assessment tools easier.
Stress among administrators, teachers, and students due to high‐stakes testing.
Collaboration‐based programs Examples Quality collaboratives Shanghai school system
Hospital engagement networks
Approach toward improving performance Improvement networks: High performing hospitals or providers are identified and work with other groups to improve patient treatment and the care process. Pairing of districts: High‐performing districts are paired with lower performing districts to exchange education development plans, curricula, and teaching materials.
Data sharing: Facilities collect and share data to monitor quality improvements and better identify best practices. Commissioned administration: A high‐performing school partners with low performers by sending experienced teachers and administrators to share successful practices and turn around their performance.
Example of success The Michigan Surgical Quality Collaborative was associated with a 2.6% drop in general and vascular surgery complications. Hospitals participating in the programs made improvements at a faster rate than those outside of the program. Zhabei District No. 8 School, located in an area with high crime rates and low student performance, was transformed from one of the lowest performing schools in its district to ranking 15 out of 30. Approximately 80% of the school's graduates go on to study at universities compared to the municipal average of 56%.

How then is it possible to improve the quality of care at lower performing hospitals without simultaneously designing an incentive system that hurts them? Lessons from the education policy are again instructive. Every 3 years the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development ranks countries by the performance of their 15‐year olds on a standardized test called the Program for International Student Assessment.[9] For the past 2 sets of rankings, Shanghai, China has topped the list. Like many attempts to generate international rankings, this one has its flaws, and Shanghai's top position has not been without controversy. For one, China is not ranked at the country‐level like other nations; yet, due to the city's status as a wealthy business and financial center, Shanghai certainly cannot be considered representative of the Chinese education system. Nevertheless, the story of how Shanghai reformed its education system and achieved its high position has important implications.

Prior to implementing reforms, Shanghai's rural outer districts struggled with less funding, high teacher turnover rates, and low test scores compared to wealthier urban districts. To reduce education disparities within the city's schools, the government of Shanghai enacted a number of policies aimed at bringing lower performers up to the same level as schools with the highest degree of student achievement.[10] The government gives schools a grade of A, B, C, or D based on the quality of their infrastructure and student performance. It then uses several programs to facilitate the exchange of staff and ideas among schools at different levels. One program pairs high‐performing districts with low‐performing districts to share education development plans, curricula, teaching materials, and best practices. Another strategycalled commissioned administrationinvolves temporary contracts between schools to exchange both administrators and experienced teachers. In addition to these approaches, the government sets a minimum level of spending for schools and transfers public funds to indigent districts to provide them with assistance to reach this level.

The notion that the very best can help the weak requires a sense of solidarity. This solidarity may falter in environments in which hospitals and physicians are in cutthroat competition. Though there will always be some tension between competition and collaboration, in most markets, competition between hospitals does not rule out collaboration. Policies can either relieve or reinforce the natural tension between competition and collaboration. This suggests that adopting reforms with the same intent as the Shanghai system is still possible in healthcare, especially through physician and other provider networks. The healthcare workforce has a rich history of cross‐organizational collaboration through mentorships, the publication of research, and participation in continuing medical education courses. The Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services' Hospital Engagement Networks, a program in which leading organizations have helped to disseminate interventions to reduce hospital acquired conditions, are an example of this approach. Quality collaborativesgroups of providers who collaborate across institutions to identify problems and best practices for improvementhave similarly shown great promise.[11] Similar approaches have been used by the Institute for Healthcare Improvement in many of their quality improvement initiatives.

Such collaboration‐based programs could be harnessed and tied to financial incentives for quality improvement. For instance, top‐performing hospitals could be incentivized to participate in a venue where they share their best practices with the lower performers in their field. Low performers, in turn, could be provided with financial assistance to implement the appropriate changes. Over time, financial assistance could be made contingent on quality improvements. By providing physicians and other providers with examples of what success looks like and assisting them with garnering the resources to reach this level, improvement would not only be incentivized, it might also become more tangible.

Although some hospitals and physicians may welcome changes to incentive systems, implementation of collaboration‐based programs would not be possible without a facilitator that is willing to underwrite program costs, provide financial incentivizes to providers, and develop a platform for collaboration. Large insurers are the most likely group to have the financial resources and widespread network to develop such programs, but that does not mean that they would be willing to experiment with this approach. This may especially be the case if cost savings and measurable improvements in quality are not immediate. Even though the results of collaboration‐based efforts have been promising, the implementation of these programs has been limited, and adoption in different contexts may not yield the same results. Collaboration‐based programs that have already shown success can serve as models, but they may need significant adaptations to meet the needs of providers in a given area.

Despite its promise, collaboration‐based strategies alone will not be enough to improve certain aspects of quality and value. Although providing physicians with knowledge on how to reduce unnecessary care, for example, could help limit overutilization, it is not sufficient to overcome the incentives of fee‐for‐service payment. In this case, broader payment reform and population‐based accountability can be paired with programs to encourage collaboration. For instance, the Blue Cross and Blue Shield of Massachusetts' Alternative Contract has used a combination of technical assistance, shared savings, and large quality bonuses to improve quality and reduce medical spending growth.[12] Collaboration‐based strategies should be seen as a complement to these broad, thoughtful reforms and a substitute for narrow incentives that encourage myopia and destructive competition.

Evidence from education and healthcare shows that penalizing the worst and rewarding the best will not shift the bell curve of performance. Such approaches are more likely to entrench and expand disparities. Instead, policy should encourage and incentivize collaboration to expand best practices that improve patient outcomes. Lessons from education provide both cautionary tales and novel solutions that might improve healthcare.

Disclosure: Nothing to report.

The United States is moving aggressively toward value‐based payment. The Department of Health and Human Services recently announced a goal to link 85% of Medicare's fee‐for‐service payments to quality or value by 2016.[1] Despite the inherent logic of paying providers for their results, evidence of the effectiveness of value‐based payment has been mixed and underwhelming. Recent reviews of pay‐for‐performancereflecting the emerging understanding of the complexities of designing successful programshave painted a more negative picture of their overall effectiveness.[2, 3] One study of over 6 million patients found that the Medicare Premier Hospital Quality Incentive Demonstration had no effect on long‐term patient outcomes including 30‐day mortality.[4] At the same time, research suggests that lower performing providers tend to have a disproportionate number of poor patients, many of whom are racial and ethnic minorities. Value‐based payment risks the dual failure of not improving health outcomes while exacerbating health inequities.

We have seen this movie before. In 2001, No Child Left Behind was enacted to improve quality and reduce inequities in K12 education in the United States. Much like healthcare, education suffers from uneven quality and wide socioeconomic disparities.[5] No Child Left Behind attempted to address these problems with new accountability measures. Based on the results from standardized tests, No Child Left Behind rewarded the highest performing schools with more funding while penalizing poor performing schools with reduced funding, and in some cases, forcing failing schools to cede control to outside operators.

In the aftermath of its implementation, however, it became clear that these incentives had not worked as intended. No Child Left Behind did not improve reading performance and was associated with improvements in math performance only for younger students.[6] These modest gains came at a high cost; consistent with teaching to the test, No Child Left Behind led to a shifting of instructional time toward math and reading and away from other subjects. It also led to widespread cheating, challenging the validity of observed performance improvements. Before No Child Left Behind was rolled out, the wealthiest school districts in the country spent as much as 10 times more than the poorest districts.[5] By penalizing the lowest performers, these gaps persisted. Schools were not given the support that they needed to improve performance.

The parallels to healthcare are striking (Table 1). Early results from Medicare's Hospital Value‐Based Purchasing and Readmission Reduction Program show that hospitals caring for more disadvantaged patients have been disproportionately penalized.[7] Similar reverse Robin Hood effects have been observed in incentive programs for physician practices.[8] Over time, financial incentive programs may substantially decrease operating revenue for hospitals and physicians caring for low‐income and minority communities. This could perpetuate the already large disparities in quality and health outcomes facing these populations. Although risk‐adjusting for socioeconomic status may alleviate these concerns in the short term, allowing low‐income or minority patients to have poorer health outcomes simply accepts that disparities exist rather than trying to reduce them.

Financial Incentive and Collaboration‐Based Programs in Healthcare and Education
Healthcare Education
National incentive programs Examples Hospital Value‐Based Purchasing Hospital Readmission‐Reduction Program No Child Left Behind
Hospital‐Acquired Conditions Penalty Program
Physician Value‐Based Payment Modifier
Approach toward improving performance Reimbursements are tied to quality and cost. Test‐based accountability: Results of standardized tests are used to determine levels of federal funding. Schools failing to meet testing goals are penalized with reductions in funding.
Bonuses are given to hospitals and providers that perform well on performance metrics. Low performers are penalized with lower reimbursements. Takeover of failing districts: Districts failing to make adequate yearly progress for 5 years in a row must implement a restructuring plan that may involve changing the school's governance arrangement, converting the school to a charter, or turning the school over to a private management company.
Unintended consequences Gaming Cheating to boost test scores.
Ignoring or neglecting areas of care that are unincentivized. Shift of instruction time toward math and reading.
Avoiding high‐risk or disadvantaged patients. States intentionally making assessment tools easier.
Stress among administrators, teachers, and students due to high‐stakes testing.
Collaboration‐based programs Examples Quality collaboratives Shanghai school system
Hospital engagement networks
Approach toward improving performance Improvement networks: High performing hospitals or providers are identified and work with other groups to improve patient treatment and the care process. Pairing of districts: High‐performing districts are paired with lower performing districts to exchange education development plans, curricula, and teaching materials.
Data sharing: Facilities collect and share data to monitor quality improvements and better identify best practices. Commissioned administration: A high‐performing school partners with low performers by sending experienced teachers and administrators to share successful practices and turn around their performance.
Example of success The Michigan Surgical Quality Collaborative was associated with a 2.6% drop in general and vascular surgery complications. Hospitals participating in the programs made improvements at a faster rate than those outside of the program. Zhabei District No. 8 School, located in an area with high crime rates and low student performance, was transformed from one of the lowest performing schools in its district to ranking 15 out of 30. Approximately 80% of the school's graduates go on to study at universities compared to the municipal average of 56%.

How then is it possible to improve the quality of care at lower performing hospitals without simultaneously designing an incentive system that hurts them? Lessons from the education policy are again instructive. Every 3 years the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development ranks countries by the performance of their 15‐year olds on a standardized test called the Program for International Student Assessment.[9] For the past 2 sets of rankings, Shanghai, China has topped the list. Like many attempts to generate international rankings, this one has its flaws, and Shanghai's top position has not been without controversy. For one, China is not ranked at the country‐level like other nations; yet, due to the city's status as a wealthy business and financial center, Shanghai certainly cannot be considered representative of the Chinese education system. Nevertheless, the story of how Shanghai reformed its education system and achieved its high position has important implications.

Prior to implementing reforms, Shanghai's rural outer districts struggled with less funding, high teacher turnover rates, and low test scores compared to wealthier urban districts. To reduce education disparities within the city's schools, the government of Shanghai enacted a number of policies aimed at bringing lower performers up to the same level as schools with the highest degree of student achievement.[10] The government gives schools a grade of A, B, C, or D based on the quality of their infrastructure and student performance. It then uses several programs to facilitate the exchange of staff and ideas among schools at different levels. One program pairs high‐performing districts with low‐performing districts to share education development plans, curricula, teaching materials, and best practices. Another strategycalled commissioned administrationinvolves temporary contracts between schools to exchange both administrators and experienced teachers. In addition to these approaches, the government sets a minimum level of spending for schools and transfers public funds to indigent districts to provide them with assistance to reach this level.

The notion that the very best can help the weak requires a sense of solidarity. This solidarity may falter in environments in which hospitals and physicians are in cutthroat competition. Though there will always be some tension between competition and collaboration, in most markets, competition between hospitals does not rule out collaboration. Policies can either relieve or reinforce the natural tension between competition and collaboration. This suggests that adopting reforms with the same intent as the Shanghai system is still possible in healthcare, especially through physician and other provider networks. The healthcare workforce has a rich history of cross‐organizational collaboration through mentorships, the publication of research, and participation in continuing medical education courses. The Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services' Hospital Engagement Networks, a program in which leading organizations have helped to disseminate interventions to reduce hospital acquired conditions, are an example of this approach. Quality collaborativesgroups of providers who collaborate across institutions to identify problems and best practices for improvementhave similarly shown great promise.[11] Similar approaches have been used by the Institute for Healthcare Improvement in many of their quality improvement initiatives.

Such collaboration‐based programs could be harnessed and tied to financial incentives for quality improvement. For instance, top‐performing hospitals could be incentivized to participate in a venue where they share their best practices with the lower performers in their field. Low performers, in turn, could be provided with financial assistance to implement the appropriate changes. Over time, financial assistance could be made contingent on quality improvements. By providing physicians and other providers with examples of what success looks like and assisting them with garnering the resources to reach this level, improvement would not only be incentivized, it might also become more tangible.

Although some hospitals and physicians may welcome changes to incentive systems, implementation of collaboration‐based programs would not be possible without a facilitator that is willing to underwrite program costs, provide financial incentivizes to providers, and develop a platform for collaboration. Large insurers are the most likely group to have the financial resources and widespread network to develop such programs, but that does not mean that they would be willing to experiment with this approach. This may especially be the case if cost savings and measurable improvements in quality are not immediate. Even though the results of collaboration‐based efforts have been promising, the implementation of these programs has been limited, and adoption in different contexts may not yield the same results. Collaboration‐based programs that have already shown success can serve as models, but they may need significant adaptations to meet the needs of providers in a given area.

Despite its promise, collaboration‐based strategies alone will not be enough to improve certain aspects of quality and value. Although providing physicians with knowledge on how to reduce unnecessary care, for example, could help limit overutilization, it is not sufficient to overcome the incentives of fee‐for‐service payment. In this case, broader payment reform and population‐based accountability can be paired with programs to encourage collaboration. For instance, the Blue Cross and Blue Shield of Massachusetts' Alternative Contract has used a combination of technical assistance, shared savings, and large quality bonuses to improve quality and reduce medical spending growth.[12] Collaboration‐based strategies should be seen as a complement to these broad, thoughtful reforms and a substitute for narrow incentives that encourage myopia and destructive competition.

Evidence from education and healthcare shows that penalizing the worst and rewarding the best will not shift the bell curve of performance. Such approaches are more likely to entrench and expand disparities. Instead, policy should encourage and incentivize collaboration to expand best practices that improve patient outcomes. Lessons from education provide both cautionary tales and novel solutions that might improve healthcare.

Disclosure: Nothing to report.

References
  1. Burwell SM. Setting value‐based payment goals—HHS efforts to improve US health care. N Engl J Med. 2015;372:897899.
  2. Herck P, Smedt D, Annemans L, Remmen R, Rosenthal MB, Sermeus W. Systematic review: effects, design choices, and context of pay‐for‐performance in health care. BMC Health Serv Res. 2010;10:247.
  3. Houle SK, McAlister FA, Jackevicius CA, Chuck AW, Tsuyuki RT. Does performance‐based remuneration for individual health care practitioners affect patient care?: a systematic review. Ann Intern Med. 2012;157(12):889899.
  4. Jha AK, Joynt KE, Orav J, Epstein AM. The long‐term effect of premier pay‐for‐ performance on patient outcomes. N Engl J Med. 2012;366:16061615.
  5. Darling‐Hammond L. Race, inequality and education accountability: the irony of ‘no child left behind.’ Race Ethn Educ. 2007;10:245260.
  6. Dee TS, Jacob BA. The impact of no child left behind on students, teachers, and schools. In: Brookings Paper on Economic Activity. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution; 2010:149194.
  7. Ryan AM. Will value‐based purchasing increase disparities in care? N Engl J Med. 2013;369:24722474.
  8. Chien AT, Wroblewski K, Damberg C, et al. Do physician organizations located in lower socioeconomic status areas score lower on pay‐for‐performance measures? J Gen Intern Med. 2012;27:548554.
  9. Loveless T. Brown Center Chalkboard. Attention OECD‐PISA: your silence on China is wrong. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institute; 2013:48.
  10. Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development. Shanghai and Hong Kong: two distinct examples of education reform in China. In: Strong Performers and Successful Reformers in Education: Lessons from PISA for the United States. Paris, France: OECD Publishing; 2010:83115.
  11. Share DA, Campbell DA, Birkmeyer N, et al. How a regional collaborative of hospitals and physicians in Michigan cut costs and improved the quality of care. Health Aff. 2011;30:636645.
  12. Song Z, Rose S, Safran DG, Landon BE, Day MP, Chernew ME. Changes in health care spending and quality 4 years into global payment. N Engl J Med. 2014;371:17041714.
References
  1. Burwell SM. Setting value‐based payment goals—HHS efforts to improve US health care. N Engl J Med. 2015;372:897899.
  2. Herck P, Smedt D, Annemans L, Remmen R, Rosenthal MB, Sermeus W. Systematic review: effects, design choices, and context of pay‐for‐performance in health care. BMC Health Serv Res. 2010;10:247.
  3. Houle SK, McAlister FA, Jackevicius CA, Chuck AW, Tsuyuki RT. Does performance‐based remuneration for individual health care practitioners affect patient care?: a systematic review. Ann Intern Med. 2012;157(12):889899.
  4. Jha AK, Joynt KE, Orav J, Epstein AM. The long‐term effect of premier pay‐for‐ performance on patient outcomes. N Engl J Med. 2012;366:16061615.
  5. Darling‐Hammond L. Race, inequality and education accountability: the irony of ‘no child left behind.’ Race Ethn Educ. 2007;10:245260.
  6. Dee TS, Jacob BA. The impact of no child left behind on students, teachers, and schools. In: Brookings Paper on Economic Activity. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution; 2010:149194.
  7. Ryan AM. Will value‐based purchasing increase disparities in care? N Engl J Med. 2013;369:24722474.
  8. Chien AT, Wroblewski K, Damberg C, et al. Do physician organizations located in lower socioeconomic status areas score lower on pay‐for‐performance measures? J Gen Intern Med. 2012;27:548554.
  9. Loveless T. Brown Center Chalkboard. Attention OECD‐PISA: your silence on China is wrong. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institute; 2013:48.
  10. Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development. Shanghai and Hong Kong: two distinct examples of education reform in China. In: Strong Performers and Successful Reformers in Education: Lessons from PISA for the United States. Paris, France: OECD Publishing; 2010:83115.
  11. Share DA, Campbell DA, Birkmeyer N, et al. How a regional collaborative of hospitals and physicians in Michigan cut costs and improved the quality of care. Health Aff. 2011;30:636645.
  12. Song Z, Rose S, Safran DG, Landon BE, Day MP, Chernew ME. Changes in health care spending and quality 4 years into global payment. N Engl J Med. 2014;371:17041714.
Issue
Journal of Hospital Medicine - 11(1)
Issue
Journal of Hospital Medicine - 11(1)
Page Number
62-64
Page Number
62-64
Publications
Publications
Article Type
Display Headline
No hospital left behind? Education policy lessons for value‐based payment in healthcare
Display Headline
No hospital left behind? Education policy lessons for value‐based payment in healthcare
Sections
Article Source
© 2015 Society of Hospital Medicine
Disallow All Ads
Correspondence Location
Address for correspondence and reprint requests: Andrew Ryan, 1420 Washington Heights, M3124, Ann Arbor, MI 48109‐2029; Telephone: 734‐936‐1311; Fax: 734‐936‐4338; E‐mail: amryan@umich.edu
Content Gating
Gated (full article locked unless allowed per User)
Gating Strategy
First Peek Free
Article PDF Media
Media Files